TEL  Vol.4 No.6 , June 2014
Trading Responses to Negative Signals
ABSTRACT

Mergers may be undertaken by giving shareholders of the target firm the right to exchange their stock for stock in the combined firm. Such stock mergers release the negative signal that the acquiring firm lacks cash. Informed traders seeking immediate gain may short sell acquirer stock or buy puts and sell calls. Liquidity traders, desiring longterm gain, may purchase stock or call options to benefit from lower stock prices, or sell stock or buy put options to maintain liquidity. This paper constructs a theoretical model in which option volume forms the bounds of the final stock price for informed traders while random stock purchase or sale volume establishes the final stock price for liquidity traders.


Cite this paper
Zikiye, M. , Abraham, R. and Harrington, C. (2014) Trading Responses to Negative Signals. Theoretical Economics Letters, 4, 378-385. doi: 10.4236/tel.2014.46049.
References
[1]   Mitchell, M., Pulvino, T. and Stafford, E. (2004) Price Pressure around Mergers. Journal of Finance, 59, 31-63. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00626.x

[2]   Easley, D.O., O’Hara, M. and Srinivas, P.S. (1998) Option Volume and Stock Prices: Evidence on Where Informed Traders Trade. Journal of Finance, 53, 431-465. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.194060

[3]   Morck, R., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1988) Management Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 293-315. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(88)90048-7

[4]   Abraham, R. and Harrington, C.W. (2013) Predicting Informed Trading at Merger Announcements. Journal of Economic Studies, 40, 658-670. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/JES-02-2012-0021

[5]   Black, F. (1986) Noise. Journal of Finance, 4, 529-543. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1986.tb
04513.x


[6]   Admati, A.R. and Pfleiderer, P. (1988) A Theory of Intraday Patterns: Volume and Price Variability. Review of Financial Studies, 1, 3-40. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/1.1.3

[7]   Bamber, L.S., Barron, O.E. and Stober, T.L. (1999) Differential Interpretations and Trading Volume. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 4, 529-543.

[8]   Abraham, R. and Harrington, C.W. (2011) Differential Information about Option Volume and Stock Volume. Journal of Derivatives and Hedge Funds, 17, 298-312.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/jdhf.2011.23

[9]   Kosti, J. and Pontiff, J. (1999) How Are Derivatives Used? Evidence from the Mutual Fund Industry. Journal of Finance, 54, 791-816. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00126

[10]   Diamond, D. and Verrecchia, R. (1987) Constraints on Short-Selling and Asset Price Adjustment to Private Information. Journal of Financial Economics, 18, 277-311. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(87)90042-0

[11]   Danielson, B.R. and Sorescu, S. (2001) Why Do Option Introductions Depress Stock Prices? A Study of Diminishing Short-Sale Constraints. DePaul University and University of Houston Working Paper.

[12]   Blau, B.M., Ness, B.F.V. and Ness, R.A.V. (2009) Short Selling and the Weekend Effect for NYSE Securities. Financial Management, 38, 603-630. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1755-053X.2009.01049.x

[13]   Elton, E.J., Gruber, M.J. and Padberg, M.W. (1976) Simple Criteria for Optimal Portfolio Selection. Journal of Finance, 31, 1341-1357. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1976.tb03217.x

[14]   Lintner, J. (1965) The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics, 47, 13-37.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1924119

[15]   Friend, I. and Blume, M. (1975) The Demand for Risky Assets. American Economic Review, 65, 900-922.

[16]   Pratt, J.W. (1964) Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large. Econometrica, 32, 122-136. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1913738

 
 
Top