ME  Vol.5 No.5 , May 2014
Agricultural Commodity Markets: Reference Point for the Real Value of a Currency
Author(s) Ian McFarlane*
ABSTRACT

Using monthly time-series data 1999-2013, the paper shows that markets for agricultural commodities provide a yardstick for real purchasing power, and thus a reference point for the real value of fiat currencies. The daily need for each adult to consume about 2800 food calories is universal; data from FAO food balance sheets confirm that the world basket of food consumed daily is non-volatile in comparison to the volatility of currency exchange rates, and so the replacement cost of food consumed provides a consistent indicator of economic value. Food commodities are storable for short periods, but ultimately perishable, and this exerts continual pressure for markets to clear in the short term; moreover, food calories can be obtained from a very large range of foodstuffs, and so most households are able to use arbitrage to select a near optimal weighting of quantities purchased. The paper proposes an original method to enable a standard of value to be established, definable in physical units on the basis of actual worldwide consumption of food goods, with an illustration of the method.


Cite this paper
McFarlane, I. (2014) Agricultural Commodity Markets: Reference Point for the Real Value of a Currency. Modern Economy, 5, 533-540. doi: 10.4236/me.2014.55050.
References
[1]   Cooper, R.N. (1999) Exchange Rate Choices (No. 1877). Harvard Institute of Economic Research, Harvard University.
ftp://dlib.info/RePEc/fth/harver/hier1877.pdf

[2]   Deaton, A. and Laroque, G. (2003) A Model of Commodity Prices after Sir Arthur Lewis. Journal of Development Economics, 71, 289-310.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3878(03)00030-0

[3]   Ghosh, J. (2011) Implications of Regulating Commodity Derivatives Markets in the USA and EU. PSL Quarterly Review, 64, 287-304.

[4]   Clapp, J. and Helleiner, E. (2012) Troubled Futures? The Global Food Crisis and the Politics of Agricultural Derivatives Regulation. Review of International Political Economy, 19, 181-207.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09692290.2010.514528

[5]   FAO (2014) The State of Food and Agriculture 2013.
www.fao.org/docrep/018/i3300e/i3300e.pdf

[6]   Powell, A. and Sturtzenegger, F. (2007) Deciding on Monetary Integration: An Operational Approach.
http://www.researchgate.net/
publication/4892971_Deciding_on_Monetary_
Integration_An_Operational_Approach/file/9c960521bb3db5ff4d.pdf


[7]   Dellas, H. and Tavlas, G. (2009) An Optimum-Currency-Area Odyssey. Journal of International Money and Finance, 28, 1117-1137.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2009.06.001

[8]   Mundell, R. (2012) The Case for a World Currency. Journal of Policy Modeling, 34, 568-578.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2012.05.011

[9]   Rogoff, K. (2001) Why Not a Global Currency? American Economic Review, 91, 247-247.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.2.243

[10]   Starr, M.A. (2006) One World, One Currency: Exploring the Issues. Contemporary Economic Policy, 24, 618-633.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/cep/byl006

[11]   Clements, K., Lan, Y. and Roberts, J. (2008) Exchange-Rate Economics for the Resources Sector. Resources Policy, 33, 102-117.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2007.12.003

[12]   Crucini, M., Shintani, M. and Tsuruga, T. (2008) Accounting for Persistence and Volatility of Good-Level Real Exchange Rates: The Role of Sticky Information. Working Paper 14381, NBER Cambridge.

[13]   Clements, K. and Fry, R. (2008) Commodity Currencies and Currency Commodities. Resources Policy, 33, 55-73.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2007.10.004

[14]   Cashin, P., Céspedes, L. and Sahay, R. (2002) Keynes, Cocoa, and Copper: In Search of Commodity Currencies. IMF Working Paper WP/02/233.

[15]   Rogoff, K. (1996) The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 647-668.

[16]   Baffes, J. and Haniotis, T. (2010) Placing the 2006/08 Commodity Price Boom into Perspective. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS5371.

[17]   Lind, K.M. (1999) Long-Run Behavior and Uncertainty in World Cereal Markets. Ministeriet for Fødevarer, Landbrugog Fiskeri, Statens Jordbrugsog Fiskeriøkonomiske Institut.

[18]   Newbold, P., Rayner, T. and Kellard, N. (2000) Long-Run Drift, Co-Movement and Persistence in Real Wheat and Maize Prices. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 51, 106-121.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-9552.2000.tb01212.x

[19]   Roberts, M. and Schlenker, W. (2009) World Supply and Demand of Food Commodity Calories. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 91, 1235-1242.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8276.2009.01290.x

[20]   Piesse, J. and Thirtle, C. (2009) Three Bubbles and a Panic: An Explanatory Review of Recent Food Commodity Price Events. Food Policy, 34, 119-129.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2009.01.001

[21]   UK Dept of Health (1991) Dietary Reference Values for Food Energy and Nutrients for the United Kingdom. HMSO, UK.

[22]   McFarlane, I. (2012) Commodity Currency: An Alternative Route to Currency Union. Modern Economy, 3, 139-144.
http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/me.2012.32019

[23]   Ravallion, M. (2008) Dollar a Day Revisited. The Selected Works of Martin Ravallion.
http://www.esocialsciences.org/GMU_Programs/Data/3.%20Dollar%20a%20Day%20Revisited.pdf

[24]   Holland, B., et al. (1991) McCance and Widdowson’s the Composition of Foods. 5th Edition, Royal Society of Chemistry, London.

 
 
Top